Land of promise An economic history of the United States

Michael Lind, 1962-

Book - 2012

Presents a historical perspective on the relationship between economic, technological, and political change by analyzing the economic growth of the United States over the course of two centuries.

Saved in:

2nd Floor Show me where

330.973/Lind
1 / 1 copies available
Location Call Number   Status
2nd Floor 330.973/Lind Checked In
Subjects
Published
New York : Harper 2012.
Language
English
Main Author
Michael Lind, 1962- (-)
Physical Description
vi, 586 p. ; 24 cm
Bibliography
Includes bibliographical references and index.
ISBN
9780061834806
9780061834813
  • 1. A Land of Promise
  • The Preindustrial Economy
  • 2. Nation Building
  • 3. The First American Economy
  • The Age of Steam
  • 4. "There Is Nothing That Cannot Be Produced by Machinery": The First Industrial Revolution
  • 5. American Systems
  • 6. Plain Mechanic Power: The Civil War and the Second Republic
  • 7. The Iron Horse and the Lightning
  • The Motor Age
  • 8. Franklin's Baby: Electricity, Automobiles, and the Second Industrial Revolution
  • 9. The Day of Combination
  • 10. The New Era
  • 11. A New Deal for America
  • 12. Arsenal of Democracy
  • 13. The Glorious Thirty Years
  • 14. The Great Dismantling
  • The Information Age
  • 15. As We May Think: The Third Industrial Revolution
  • 16. The Bubble Economy
  • 17. The Next American Economy
  • Acknowledgments
  • Notes
  • Index
Review by New York Times Review

Whatever their political party, American leaders have generally subscribed to one of two competing economic philosophies. One is a small-government Jeffersonian perspective that abhors bigness and holds that prosperity flows from competition among independent businessmen, farmers and other producers. The other is a Hamiltonian agenda that believes a large, powerful country needs large, powerful organizations. The most important of those organizations is the federal government, which serves as a crucial partner to private enterprise, building roads and schools, guaranteeing loans and financing scientific research in ways that individual businesses would not. Today, of course, Republicans are the Jeffersonians and Democrats are the Hamiltonians. But it hasn't always been so. The Jeffersonian line includes Andrew Jackson, the leaders of the Confederacy, William Jennings Bryan, Louis Brandeis, Barry Goldwater and Ronald Reagan. The Hamiltonian line includes George Washington, Henry Clay, Abraham Lincoln, William McKinley, both Roosevelts and Dwight Eisenhower. Michael Lind's "Land of Promise" uses this divide to offer an ambitious economic history of the United States. The book is rich with details, more than a few of them surprising, and its subject is central to what is arguably the single most important question facing the country today: How can our economy grow more quickly, more sustainably and more equitably than it has been growing, both to maintain the United States' position as the world's pre-eminent power and to improve the lives of its citizens? Lind, a founder of the New America Foundation in Washington and the author of several political histories, acknowledges from the beginning that his thesis will make some readers uncomfortable. "In the spirit of philosophical bipartisanship, it would be pleasant to conclude that each of these traditions of political economy has made its own valuable contribution to the success of the American economy and that the vector created by these opposing forces has been more beneficial than the complete victory of either would have been," he writes. "But that would not be true," he continues. "What is good about the American economy is largely the result of the Hamiltonian developmental tradition, and what is bad about it is largely the result of the Jeffersonian producerist school." Hamiltonian development built the Erie Canal, the transcontinental railroad, the land-grant universities and the Interstate highway system. In the process, the United States became a giant, interconnected market, a place where companies like Standard Oil, General Motors, John Deere and Sears Roebuck could thrive. The government - and the American military in particular - also played the most important role in financing innovation at its early stages. The industries that produced the jet engine, the radio (and, by extension, the television), radar, penicillin, synthetic rubber and semiconductors all stemmed from government-financed research or procurement. The Defense Department literally built the Internet. The United States is like "a gigantic boiler," Sir Edward Grey, a British foreign secretary during World War I, said, according to Winston Churchill. "Once the fire is lighted under it, there is no limit to the power it can generate." Lind's aim is to make Sir Edward's point in the active voice: the government has often lighted the flame, and big business has often generated the power. And Lind has a strong case to make. He cleverly notes that Jeffersonians themselves often have a change of heart when they find themselves running the country and responsible for its well-being. As president, Jefferson altered his position on federal support for canals, roads and manufacturers. His successor, James Madison, signed a bill creating a national bank, having previously denounced the idea. The leaders of the Confederacy, after decrying centralized power, realized they needed an economic machine to finance a war and started "a crash program of state-guided industrialization from above that was more Hamiltonian than Hamilton," Lind writes. Modern Jeffersonians, like Reagan and George W. Bush, have campaigned on spending cuts, only to expand government while in office. For all its logical rigor, however, the book's thesis does suffer from one basic flaw. Lind never quite explains how the United States has ended up as the richest large country in the world, with per capita income about 20 percent higher than Sweden's or Canada's, almost 30 percent higher than Germany's and almost 500 percent higher than China's. If anything, other countries have pursued more Hamiltonian policies in many ways than the United States, without quite the same success. What, then, can explain American economic exceptionalism? Education plays an important role (and receives only sporadic mention in the book). This country long had the most educated, skilled work force in the world, which, as other economic histories have persuasively shown, helped American workers to be among the best paid. Beyond education, the United States also has a culture that is arguably different from that of any other power - more individualistic, more risk-taking, more comfortable with the workings of the market. If you were looking for a name for this culture, you might choose Jeffersonian. Lind, I expect, would dispute that a Jeffersonian culture has played a major role in creating prosperity. Yet readers will emerge from the 586 pages of "Land of Promise," despite its many charms, without hearing an argument that fully engages with its opponents. American economic history, in Lind's telling, has been a series of three revolutions and counterrevolutions, with each revolution tied to an actual war. The economic decision that awaited the victorious founders in the 1780s was whether to create a system that complemented the British economy by providing resources for Britain's emerging industries and customers for its products, or to create a full-blown national competitor. Southerners, understandably, preferred a partnership, since they had the resources, particularly cotton. The Southern view was also informed by centuries of history in which global living standards had been largely unchanged. In this zero-sum, Malthusian world, a simple agrarian economy made sense. It seemed to maximize individual freedom and avoid the pollution and concentration of power that industry brought. "While we have land to labor," Jefferson wrote in 1782, "let us never wish to see our citizens occupied at a workbench." Hamiltonians put more faith in economic change and progress. They subscribed to the ideas of John Locke, the pre-eminent political philosopher of the American Revolution, in which military power stemmed from economic growth and population growth. Hamiltonians encouraged the immigration of inventors and skilled workers (Hamilton himself was an immigrant) and pushed public support for infant industries as well as tariffs to protect them. They also advocated a modern, centralized financial system to pay for the needed investments. The grander ambitions of the Hamiltonians largely won out, but the victory was temporary. Even as the country benefited enormously, some people did not The changes also threatened entrenched interests and stoked classically American fears of centralization. Soon Andrew Jackson, more Jeffersonian than the namesake, was on the counterattack, opposing federal road building and closing the national bank. THESE cycles have continued, more or less, for 200 years. Lincoln - a state legislator during Jackson's time who fought for federal investment - was the great Hamiltonian of the 19th century. After the South left the Union, Lincoln, with the backing of Congress, was able to undertake an investment bonanza that Southern representatives had blocked, building rail lines, roads and colleges. Many of these programs would ultimately help industrialize the South. Hamiltonians, obviously, did not always make the right investments. The first aviator the federal government backed was Samuel Pierpont Langley, the director of the Smithsonian Institution, whose test flights crashed into the Potomac. But the cost of such failures paled next to the returns of the successes. The military soon became the Wright brothers' first client and allowed them, and American aviation more generally, to flourish before a private market for it existed. Among the joys of Lind's book are small, little-known stories like the one about the Wright brothers that have clear relevance today. I expect I will be returning to the index of "Land of Promise" with some frequency. Another joy is Lind's attempt to rehabilitate figures to whom history has not been kind. McKinley may have had some cronyism problems, yet he also fought to modernize the American economy and was ahead of his time on civil rights. Wall Street tycoons of the 19th century like J. P. Morgan may have been rapacious, yet they also provided crucial financing for inventors like Thomas Edison. Even Herbert Hoover, whom Lind criticizes for the usual reasons, receives praise for creating the (albeit too modest) forerunners of the New Deal and World War II mobilization. That mobilization provided the most important Hamiltonian victories since Lincoln's time. A generation of bipartisan presidents afterward, from Harry Truman to Gerald Ford, largely accepted the world Roosevelt left them. Then came the Great Dismantling, to use Lind's term, when first Jimmy Carter and, much more aggressively, Reagan moved toward a less centralized, more laissez-faire economy. These decades have seen far slower income growth for most Americans than the previous century. The chapters on the most recent years are a fairly standard liberal version of events, with deregulation and modern finance as the main antagonists. If you think airline deregulation was an abomination because service can be wretched and airline bankruptcies are common, you will like Lind's telling. If you instead prefer to concentrate on the fact that middle-class Americans can now afford to fly regularly or that air travel has never been safer, you will not be persuaded. But Lind ends on a stronger note. The major problems facing the United States today, he argues, are ones that demand Hamiltonian solutions. True innovation, of the kind that lifts living standards for the masses, cannot come from lone inventors. It requires resources that only large organizations have. It also requires skilled people, be they well-educated natives or immigrants admitted because of the skills they can bring. The notion that the United States has stopped making many large-scale investments that bring great returns is not, in Lind's view, surprising. American economic history tends to run in cycles. Yes, our roads and bridges are dilapidated. Our broadband infrastructure is not quite world-class. Our schools, including many colleges, can no longer claim to be the finest. But the economic need for change will eventually create the political will for it. "Land of Promise" ends on as optimistic a note as the title suggests, though it also acknowledges that failure is an option. David Leonhardt, the Washington bureau chief of The Times, won a Pulitzer Prize last year for his columns on the economy.

Copyright (c) The New York Times Company [April 29, 2012]
Review by Booklist Review

Lind, political journalist and historian, offers a broad examination of American economic history, citing the common argument that technological and economic innovation comes in bursts of change, followed by long periods in which the implications of the latest innovations are worked out. Over time, during a war or depression, the political order dissolves, and a new American republic is built. We learn about the inventors, entrepreneurs, financiers, and statesmen in America's economic history as well as essential contributions from groups such as southern slaves, immigrants, and women laborers during WWII (Rosie the Riveters). The author suggests that future historians will determine that governments since the 2008 Great Recession are doing too little rather than too much as they succumb to excessive fears of deficits and national debt and excessive optimism about the self-healing powers of the market, and the post-2008 wreckage of the middle class requires a specific strategy to rebuild it. Although all readers will not agree with Lind, this is an excellent book for history enthusiasts.--Whaley, Mary Copyright 2010 Booklist

From Booklist, Copyright (c) American Library Association. Used with permission.
Review by Publisher's Weekly Review

Lind (Vietnam: The Necessary War) delivers a conventional story of America's technological transformation in parallel with an imaginative account of the 200-year tug-of-war between Alexander Hamilton's and Thomas Jefferson's economic philosophies. Lind, cofounder of the New America Foundation, prefers Hamilton's vision of an activist central government that, he argues, produces economic growth. But that theory enjoyed only spotty success after 1800 and none after Andrew Jackson rejected it. It revived with Lincoln's support of railroads, national banking, and a tariff-based import system. Jeffersonian laissez-faire returned, but, the author points out, even the Jeffersonians supported government intervention in favor of small businesses. Lind hails the New Deal era from FDR through Nixon as a Hamiltonian triumph during which the economy mushroomed, middle-class mass consumerism appeared, and poverty plummeted. Carter and Reagan began the Jeffersonian reaction: antigovernment rhetoric accompanied by deregulation. Instead of a flourishing free market, says Lind, the result has been not productive industry but wage stagnation, crumbling infrastructure, and a sluggish economy driven by boom-and-bust speculation and rising debt. The coda offers a prescription for how the next Hamiltonian cycle should fix matters, but asserts that Jeffersonianism rules today. Lind paints a vivid if dismal picture. (Apr.) (c) Copyright PWxyz, LLC. All rights reserved.

(c) Copyright PWxyz, LLC. All rights reserved
Review by Library Journal Review

Lind (policy director, economic growth program, New America Fdn.; columnist, Salon.com) argues that an ideological battle between the ideas of Thomas Jefferson and Alexander Hamilton has shaped the country's evolving relationship between state and economy. It would be difficult to find a book with more fascinating biographical details, statistical vignettes, and obscure but truly engaging, eye-opening details of U.S. economic history. However, while Lind is an excellent historian, his venture into economics is tainted throughout by his political philosophy and the strained interpretations it demands. His work is weakened by his frequent ill-formed and unjustified explanations of economic outcomes and realities. Its most enlightening chapters, on the politics of railroad development or the economics of U.S. war efforts, are overshadowed by the author's mercantilist worldview that privileges relative national advancement over absolute economic growth. VERDICT Despite its shortcomings, the book's value is in revealing, behind every generalized economic data point, stories of real people with real names and real skills who contributed to U.S. economic success and made the country a true "land of promise." [See Prepub Alert, 8/21/11.]-Jekabs Bikis, Dallas (c) Copyright 2012. Library Journals LLC, a wholly owned subsidiary of Media Source, Inc. No redistribution permitted.

(c) Copyright Library Journals LLC, a wholly owned subsidiary of Media Source, Inc. No redistribution permitted.
Review by Kirkus Book Review

The director of the New America Foundation's Economic Growth Program charts the technological innovations and the political response to those changes that have marked our economic history. Many of us mistakenly think politics will change the world when, in fact, it's the steamship plowing against the current, the railroad stretching across the nation, the electricity lighting our homes or the personal computer connecting us to the world that end up most intimately altering our daily lives. It's been the job of our politics to catch up and wrestle with those changes. Lind (The American Way of Strategy: U.S. Foreign Policy and the American Way of Life, 2006, etc.) divides American economic history into three epochs, beginning with the First Republic "founded on water and undermined by steam." Even as Hamilton and Jefferson's competing visions struggled to shape character of the new nation, the Industrial Revolution was already underway. Absorbing grand innovations, writes Lind, leads to periods of misalignment, when "the institutions of the economy and the polity drift further and further apart." Great crises follow, and the U.S. had to pass through the Civil War to found a Second Republic, itself threatened by the coming widespread adaptation of electricity and the internal combustion engine. The nation had to endure a Great Depression and World War II before today's Third Republic emerged, an Information Age whose technological roots can be traced to those tumultuous decades. The cycle continues as we await another Republic born in the aftermath of today's Great Recession. With dozens of short entries on the businessmen, financiers, inventors and industrialists who helped transform the country and the political leaders and public servants responsible for handling the social consequences--highest marks go to those in the Hamiltonian tradition like Henry Clay, Lincoln and FDR--Lind memorably vivifies this constant churn of economic activity and political reconstruction. Timely, big-picture analysis that supplies vital context to our current economic and political moment.]] Copyright Kirkus Reviews, used with permission.

Copyright (c) Kirkus Reviews, used with permission.